Showing posts with label Inflation expectations. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Inflation expectations. Show all posts

Saturday, August 6, 2011

The Disaster That Is Federal Reserve policy.

Tim Duy nicely sums up how incompetent Fed policy has been over the past few years.
Bottom Line:  The market nosedive does not yet guarantee Fed action in the near future.  History has shown the Fed tends to react with a lag.  They should have learned better by now, but if they had learned anything, they would not have pushed forward with hawkish rhetoric earlier this year.  Arguably, they will hold firm, let the markets think they are out of the game and further bid down implied inflation expectations, and then, once the damage is done, up the level of stimulus.  Terrible way to run an economy, I know.
I think this is exactly right, and it shows how misguided the Fed is right now. If the Fed is looking at market inflation expectations (and they have made it clear they are) they seem to be forgetting that those expectations have expected monetary policy built into them. To the extent that expectations deviate from the Fed's implicit goal (2-3%), they already represent policy failure.

To use a "Sumnerian" analogy, it would be like the captain of the Titanic looking at market expectations of their eventual destination and saying "Expectations say we'll be in New York City on time, looks like my job is done!", without realizing those expectations exist because he is expected to appropriately react to changing conditions (and avoid icebergs!).

It's actually worse than this though, because the Fed will never make up for "lost" NGDP growth. They've already made it quite clear they aren't comfortable with inflation above ~2% under any circumstances, and so we are left with a permanently lower NGDP and 
price level trend.

To put this into perspective, in 2008, when the financial crisis began, a good guess for 2018 NGDP would have been about $26 trillion. Right now, even if we get 5% NGDP from this point forward it will be just over $22 trillion! Over the course of a decade this will have added up to a $27 trillion* difference in nominal income! Too bad for anyone paying wage contracts, but at least employees got a nice real wage boost! And sure, it hurts debtors, but investors have done fantastically! 
You may detect a hint of sarcasm. So much for the "trade offs" of inflation/deflation between creditors and debtors that some are pushing.

* I originally mistakenly wrote it would result in a $105 trillion difference because I forgot I was dealing with quarterly annualized numbers.

Wednesday, June 15, 2011

How QE2's Announcement and Premature End Affected Asset Prices

Firstly, let me justify the beginning and end dates for QE2.

I consider August 27, 2010 to be the effective beginning of QE2. On this day Bernanke delivered the Jackson Hole speech in which he first hinted at another round of quantitative easing for the purpose of stimulating aggregate demand.

I consider April 27, 2011 to be the effective end of QE2 (although it would be more accurate to say "the end of any chance for additional easing of any kind unless things get much much worse"). The key quote by Bernanke was this :

“The trade-offs are getting — are getting less attractive at this point. Inflation has gotten higher. Inflation expectations are a bit higher. It’s not clear that we can get substantial improvements in payrolls without some additional inflation risk."

He hasn't given any indication he has changed his mind since, or that he plans to pursue any other form of easing.

Now that you know where I'm coming from, let's look at some asset prices!


No form of assets responded more clearly to the announcement and effective end of QE2 than equities did. Higher equity prices reflect better economic expectations and those expectations can become a self fulfilling prophecy through Tobin's q and wealth effects. Perhaps more importantly, higher stock prices also partially reflect a lower demand for dollars and that decreased demand immediately increases nominal spending. Also note the fall after QE2's "end".



Similarly, inflation expectations seem to have been strongly influenced by QE2's announcement. Again note the fall since QE2's end.


Treasury yields also noticeably rose in response to QE2. Many have pointed out that QE2 was supposed to reduce yields and have pointed to their rise as evidence against QE2's effectiveness (ignoring equity prices and inflation expectations), but higher yields were actually reflecting higher inflation real growth expectations. As Milton Friedman and Frederick Mishkin have pointed out, interest rates are NOT a reliable indicator of monetary policy and low interest rates can (and do) signal that money is tight. Higher interest rates usually reflect a healthier economy when rates are this low. Unsurprisingly, the lower rates of the past month have been associated with worsening economic conditions.


Finally, the dollar has almost certainly fallen as a result to QE2. A falling dollar can be a bad sign if it is associated with high inflation (or supply side issues), but high inflation is still not a concern. In this case, a falling dollar helped increase net exports (by cheapening domestic goods) and as reflected less dollar hoarding (which is associated with lower V and more NGDP at any given supply of money). And once again, just as any prospects for additional easing ended the dollar began to rise.

Several excellent economists including John Cochran and James Hamilton have expressed doubts about the effectiveness of QE2. It's true that from a purely mechanical perspective, QE2 was likely irrelevant. So why the impact on markets?

The most likely explanation is that QE2 impacted medium term (2-10 years in the future) NGDP expectations. Anything the Fed can do to convince people that they will push for a higher NGDP in the future will improve expectations. Improved expectations have immediate effects on NGDP as they raise expected inflation/real growth and reduce the demand for dollars (thereby increasing V) today.

If this is the case, why does the Fed seem so uncomfortable with higher future NGDP? I think it's mostly a year over year % change issue versus a level targeting one. The Fed is worried that even temporarily higher rates of inflation and NGDP growth (to catch up to past trends) will be hard to push back down. That would be reasonable if expected inflation was above 3%, but at barely 2% these concerns are completely unjustified. The Fed is also likely concerned about bubbles, but with unemployment at 9% and a tremendous amount of slack in the economy, those concerns need much more justification and evidence backing them before they can be legitimately used to prevent easier policy.

(Half way through creating this post I saw that Marcus Nunes beat me to it and posted something very similar. He makes somewhat different -- although equally valid -- points)

In the next few days I'll post something similar regarding the impact of QE2 on economic data.

Fed Funds and Aggregate Demand Watch 6/15/2011



S&P 500
April 27 : 1357
May 26 : 1325.69
June 8 : 1279.56
June 15 : 1265.42

Treasuries
2 year
April 27: 0.64
May 26 : 0.48
June 8 : 0.38
June 15 : 0.38
10 Year
April 27 : 3.35
May 26 : 3.06
June 8 : 2.94
June 15 : 2.97
30 Year
April 27 : 4.45
May 26 : 4.22
June 8 : 4.19
June 15 : 4.20

Inflation Expectations
2 year inflation swaps
April 27 : 2.65
May 26 : 2.12
June 8 : 2.01
June 15 : 2.00
5 Year TIPS Breakeven rate
April 27 : 2.35
May 26 : 2.07
June 8 : 2.02
June 15 : 2.01
10 Year TIPS spread
April 27 : 2.6
May 26 : 2.34
June 8 : 2.27
June 15 : 2.29
30 Year TIPS spread
April 27 : 2.68
May 26 : 2.47
June 8 : 2.45
June 15 : 2.44

Bloomberg Commodity Index
April 27 : 1766.98
May 26 : 1684.28
June 8 : 1713.68
June 15 : 1674.20

EUR USD
April 27 : 1.4738
May 26 : 1.4129
June 8 : 1.4577
June 15 : 1.4172

(Data from bloomberg.com)

Thanks to the beating stocks took today, data were once again mixed compared to last week. Stocks and commodities are signaling lower aggregate demand expectations, while the Euro/Dollar exchange rate and federal funds futures are signaling higher expectations. Despite a better than expected retail sales number (which was still negative), economic data has continued to disappoint. At this point, I consider "mixed" markets good news.

Tuesday, June 7, 2011

An Unsurprisingly Unsurprising Press Conference

But Bloomberg gets it. It can't be any more obvious markets want easier money. That's a pretty clear refutation of the US being in a liquidity trap. If markets believe monetary policy can work, then monetary policy can work (by reducing the demand for money).

That only leaves those who believe additional monetary stimulus will cause undesirably high inflation... But inflation expectations remain low, and prices are still below their long term trend.

One-Year Chart for BE 5 Year (USGGBE05:IND)

In addition, whatever Bernanke means by "faster growth" isn't fast enough, and I don't expect stronger growth until the Fed takes additional actions.